Jump to content

I hope this puts the NCAA out of business.


HooverOutlaw

Recommended Posts

1 hour ago, Sweetlarry said:

Holy shit! A deadspin article?!? 
 

Fucking eh carnalito! I’m woke now! 
 

😂

In last month’s antitrust case in Oakland challenging the artificial caps on athlete compensation, the NCAA’s defense included the restatement of an imaginary economic principle that is fundamental to its existence: College athletes shouldn’t make money, the NCAA argued, because if players were paid above some magical line, consumer demand for the product would plummet and the golden goose would stop laying its billion-dollar eggs.

 
 
 

But when pressed as to where that magical line is, the answer always changes. Prior to 1956, the answer was something like “anything at all” since as an organization, the NCAA maintained that even athletic scholarships were pay and thus anyone getting an athletic scholarship had forfeited their amateurism. As economist Roger Noll testified in Oakland, by this standard, no school in Division I is presenting amateur sports, other than those in the Ivy League. (You can read the public version of Noll’s direct testimony yourself. This element of his testimony appears at pages 9 through 11.)

The thing is, though, that even way back then, the NCAA’s claim—that fan interest would evaporate if schools did not agree to cap compensation at the magical line between amateur and professional—was false. Patently, demonstrably false.

Prior to 1948, the NCAA never asserted any right to actually enforce its amateur status, leaving it to each conference to assess its own fans’ competing desires—for high quality play on the one hand and for amateurism on the other—and make offers to athletes consistent with its own assessment. Schools did different things. Big Ten schools did not give scholarships, but they gave their athletes jobs on campus. (Yes, they were employees of their schools despite Mark Emmert’s claim that such a thing is incompatible with college sports.) SEC schools gave athletic scholarships that included cash stipends. Starting in 1948, the NCAA tried, but failed to enforce its rules, and did not succeed in establishing real national oversight until 1956.

So we have a hypothesis, which just so happens to be a crux of the NCAA’s legal argument: Paying higher than the amateur line will destroy demand for college sports.

 

And we have had multiple tests of that hypothesis: Many schools in major college football and basketball paid their athletes more than that.

College sports are more popular and more profitable than ever. The only scientific conclusion is to reject the hypothesis.


Rather than heed the scientific method, the NCAA’s response is always to move the goalposts. But of course the claim that people only watch college sports because the athletes are kept artificially poor is, at core, utter rubbish, and the NCAA keeps moving the magical line higher.

Starting in 1956, the NCAA defined the level of compensation beyond which one would be considered a professional as a Grant-in-Aid and set the GIA limit as tuition, fees, room, board, books and necessary supplies, plus a $15-a-month stipend. (Remember that $15 went a lot father back then. It’d be like $140 a month now). This stipend was known as “laundry money” because in the sexist culture of the 1950s, it was seen as impossible for a young man to do his own laundry, so of course he needed money to pay a woman to do it for him.

So for the period from 1956–1976, we had a test of the view that any money for athletes would kill college sports. Yet despite the scholarships and stipends, college sports remained extremely popular. So right away, this was proof that the former line, extant for a half-century, had been wrong.

Then in the 1970s, America as a whole hit a bad patch, economically. Inflation was high, growth was slow. Basically, everyone felt like they were earning less and things were costing a lot more. Schools were no different, so they gathered in Chicago in August 1975 and declared that the amateurism standard that had served the industry for the previous two decades was too generous and needed to be curtailed, lest college sports die. Not because fans felt athletes were insufficiently amateur, but rather because schools’ competitive urges were leading them to spend more than was prudent in those tough economic ties. In other words, it was a decision to fix prices to save money.

I’ve read the minutes of the meeting—they are available in hard copy at the University of New Mexico and Northwest Louisiana State – but if you don’t want to travel there, you can see some of the relevant quotes in the public version of another of the court filings in the Oakland case (read pages 51-56). If you read it, you will see that no one in the room expressed a single concern that the problem was with alienating fans. It was, in every sense, we’re spending too much money and we’d like to spend less.

There is an economic term for when a group of competitors agrees to a maximum price each will spend on a needed input to their product. The term is “cost-cutting cartel” and that is what the NCAA revealed itself to be when, starting in 1976, it rolled out its new definition of amateurism by redefining the GIA to exclude necessary supplies, to exclude any book recommended by the professor but not required, and to exclude the “laundry money” stipend.

So now we had a new hypothesis to test. If the NCAA’s assertion is that consumer demand will decline if athletes receive more than their definition of amateurism, then it should hold that when athletes received less money, demand should have immediately shot up. There is no evidence that it did. And yet that rule remained on the books as the NCAA’s definition of the line beyond which the sport would collapse, all the way up until Aug. 1, 2015, when the magical line moved yet again.

During that period from 1976 through 2015, multiple lawsuits were filed, and multiple arguments were made by the NCAA that if athletes got more than the GIA limit, the sport would collapse. In 2007, the NCAA brought out several witnesses who said that if athletes got cash payments akin to laundry money (but updated with the less sexist term of “cost of attendance” stipends), that would amount to “pay for play.” These witnesses included current NCAA VP Lynn Holzman, former NCAA VP David Berst, and expert MIT economist Jerry Hausman.

(A brief side excursion on the term “pay for play”: never use it, unless you are quoting someone. It is a term of propaganda. When a member of Congress takes a bribe, we call it “pay for play.” It connotes bribery. But in the context of 2007 or 2013, providing an athlete with a COA stipend was not a proposed bribe, it was a form of compensation for services. When you call a plumber over to fix a leaking sink, it is not “pay for plumb.” When a coach gets $10 million to coach an FBS football team it is not “pay for coach.” It’s just good ol’ American compensation. So every time you say “pay for play” you are, wittingly or unwittingly, propagating propaganda. Don’t do it.)

In 2013, the NCAA brought out expert Berkeley economist Dan Rubinfeld, former chief economist for the U.S. DOJ, who argued (under penalty of perjury) that if athletes got more than the GIA limit, then “amateur college athletics, including amateur college football and college basketball, but also including dozens of other amateur sports … would not exist.” (You can read this at page 20 of his report for the O’Bannon case.)

Well, as we know, in the wake of the O’Bannon trial, when many witnesses testified that they did not see any justification for capping pay below cost of attendance, even though the NCAA had been doing so for almost 40 years, the NCAA relented and allowed the Power 5 conferences to start paying more. Laundry money was back, baby, in the form of COA stipends which in some cases exceeded $6,000 per year.

And so we had yet another test of the NCAA’s hypothesis. And now, with more compensation allowed, college sports’ popularity did not drop and did not spike, but continued to grow at the same pace. Athletes are now being paid more, and nevertheless college sports continue to exist!

Did that make the NCAA admit their inability to identify the magical line, or admit any doubts as to whether there even was a magical line? Not at all. It denied that the change from the old cap to the new cap was even relevant because, as it now claimed, the cap did not really change at all. The explanation for this stretches belief. Beginning in 2004, schools had been allowed to give the most academically gifted athletes an income supplement from an academic scholarship to provide that COA stipend, so the fact that in 2015, suddenly everyone was getting the stipend was not a change at all.

This does not demonstrate what the NCAA thinks it does. If the change came in 2004, then the fact that NO ONE EVEN NOTICED is very strong evidence that the 1976 line was wrong. But back in 2004, of course, the argument was that it was okay because this supplemental income was unrelated to athletics, and indeed, it was alleged that if every athlete, not just those on academic scholarships, could get their full COA, it would be “pay for play”—exactly what happened in 2015, when the NCAA would retroactively claim that universally available COA stipends were simply status quo.


See what’s going on here? No matter what the prior justification was for the position of magical line, when the line changes the argument becomes that we all simply misunderstood the old line. This is gaslighting—when a person or organization in power tells you that your own memory of a contradiction is faulty, that rather than their having been wrong, you are the one who’s failing to remember how things really were, and thus can’t understand how they are now.

Here is what NCAA gaslighting looked like in the recent court case in Oakland, where University of Virginia economist Kenneth Elzinga claimed that the NCAA rules on what constitutes the magic line had never changed during the hundred years of history I’ve laid out above.

Elzinga testified (on pages 19-20), emphasis his:

The essential features or goals of the NCAA’s amateurism definition have remained consistent. When one compares the language of the NCAA’s current definition of amateurism to the definition adopted in 1912, the language is similar… The essential features of both definitions are the same. First, student-athletes are those who play the game for the sake of the game, i.e., “for the exercise, training, and social pleasures,” or for the “education and . . . physical, mental and social benefits.” Second, student-athletes do not play for “any material or economic advantage or reward,” or “for pay in any form.” That is, they do not play for pay. These two strands are not separate; they are complementary. The opposite of playing for pay is to play for the sake of the game and vice versa. Both definitions refer to the attitude or state of mind of the student-athlete. The earlier definition says “[t]he natural or primary attitude of mind and motives in play determines amateurism,” and the latter says “tudent participation in intercollegiate athletics is an avocation.”

Do you see where he’s sneaking a rabbit into his testimonial hat? He’s not saying the RULES didn’t change—the actual definition of the magic line—he’s just saying the justification has never changed. In both 1912 and 2018, the NCAA has claimed that if they don’t restrict earnings, athletes will not be amateurs. But Elzinga’s testimony does not engage with where that slippery line might be.

The line even changed during the course of Elzinga’s work on the case. In his first report in the matter, he explained that even “a penny” of non-educational compensation would destroy demand for college sports.

But when confronted with evidence that many athletes already get hundreds of dollars of such non-educational compensation, he denied having meant it, claiming he was being taken too literally, that he was quoting someone else, and, anyway, some token payment above the magical line was fine. You can see the goalposts moving if you compare his early testimony to the revised version he submitted a year later in the run-up to the trial itself, where he testified (on page 32), emphasis mine:

“Once a student-athlete’s cost of attendance and the amounts incidental to his or her participation in college athletics have been covered, to receive additional amounts in return for athletic performance is to be paid, i.e., to cease to be an amateur and to become a professional.”

That’s a pro-NCAA economist changing his definition of the magical line in real-time.

This goalpost-shifting can also be seen in the testimony of NCAA VP Kevin Lennon. In the run-up to the trial, at an unguarded moment (under oath) Lennon had testified (at pages 72-73) that these sorts of additional payments (what the NCAA calls “benefits incidental to participation”) are “not related to the principle of amateurism.”

A month or two later, as the implications of this admission became more evident, Lennon was asked to submit a lawyer-drafted recantation, in which he explained that he only meant that “granular changes to certain NCAA rules could be made without impacting amateurism...In other instances, however, the proposed benefit may pose a greater risk to amateurism as a potential device for pay-for-play, requiring the membership to adopt limits to minimize that risk.”

In other words, how could you possibly think that when he said the rules about paying athletes with Xboxes for going to a bowl game were “not related to the principle of amateurism,” that he possibly meant anything other than that those rules are totally related to preserving amateurism? Gaslighting.

Another piece of evidence brought up in Oakland was the notion that from 1956 forward, once the NCAA grabbed the power to enforce its magic line du jour, schools frequently broke the rules. Athletes lost their eligibility, and even once, when SMU was found to have egregiously flaunted the rules, it was banned from having a football team for two years, the so-called death penalty.

In his testimony (at pages 51-55), Roger Noll rightly pointed to these as examples of the magical line being crossed without harm to fans’ interest in college sports. College football is orders of magnitude bigger now than it was when SMU was executed, and has thrived in the face of numerous programs committing violations.

My favorite example of this sort of “scandal” was when Ohio State players had the temerity to sell their own property to pay for tattoos, and were suspended for half a season—an extreme penalty in the NCAA system—but were allowed to play in the Sugar Bowl against Arkansas because everyone wanted to see that looming clash of the titans. The TV ratings were historic because it promised to be the highest quality of football. No one seemed to care that a large chunk of the Ohio State players were not amateurs under the rule in place at the time.

In the Oakland case, Professor Elzinga provided the sleight-of-hand needed to explain this away too. What mattered was not whether there were infractions here or there, but just that the public knew that the NCAA was on the beat, patrolling to make sure it only happened occasionally, and that when it was caught, it was punished severely. Each example was therefore not evidence disproving the hypothesis, but supporting it. He testified (at page 36):

“Even if rising revenues did establish that punishing rules violators has not undermined the popularity of college sports, that would not support a conclusion that fans of college sports do not care about amateurism. The fact that the NCAA conducted those investigations demonstrates to the public that the NCAA does take amateurism seriously, and is willing to mete out punishment when violations call for it. That’s the sort of information that should be more likely to encourage the public about NCAA enforcement, rather than discourage it.”


And so we come to the scandal of the day, the criminal fraud and corruption cases currently being tried in federal court in New York City, in which several non-NCAA members are accused of defrauding major college basketball programs by providing side payments to athletes to ensure they attended those schools. The government’s theory is basically nuts, because it relies on the premise that when a sneaker company pays an athlete to go to a school that wears that company’s shoes, that school is somehow harmed—of course, we all know that schools hate getting great athletes who can pack their arenas and help generate donations.

Both the government and the defendants in the case admit that money was given to athletes. In some cases, these athletes played for those schools—e.g., Dennis Smith played a year for N.C. State and the Federal Government alleges, and the defendants do not dispute, that he received $40,000 on top of his scholarship to do so. He was, so to speak, paid and he played. And no one cared. Where’s the magical line?

Smith finished his college career without detection by the NCAA’s beat cops. The allegation of Smith’s payment was leveled a year ago. N.C. State has not been charged with an NCAA violation. N.C. State has not seen its fans storm to the athletic department offices and demand that the AD or the compliance staff be fired for failing to catch this egregious violation. No. One. Cares.

So what should we expect to see when college basketball tips off next month?

If you believe the NCAA’s “amateurism” hypothesis, it’s now clear that many of the best athletes in college basketball were paid by third parties to play for their AAU teams, and many were also paid to choose a school based on the shoe company those schools have contract with, so the inescapable result is that consumer demand for college basketball will plummet because of systemic payment above the magic line that was not kept under control by rigorous NCAA enforcement efforts.

Once again, the “Amateurism is Essential” argument will be put to the test. Be ready for it, because if the NCAA is correct, then College Basketball May Die Next Month. People might boycott in droves. And if so, the elusive magical line will finally have been found.

But if instead what we see is business as usual, maybe this time we’ll finally stop accepting the ever-shifting goalposts, the amateurism gaslighting, and just acknowledge that what fans care about is college sports played by college athletes, no matter what they’re earning.


Andy Schwarz is an antitrust economist and partner at OSKR, an economic consulting firm specializing in expert witness testimony. He is part of a new project, HBLeague.com, working to create a non-amateur version of college sports. Follow him on Twitter

Link to comment
Share on other sites

4 hours ago, The Guru said:

He's an idiot.

He still thinks that the NCAA is a "middleman" and that the schools should create their own leagues.

The schools created the NCAA.

If the NCAA "went out of business" then the schools would just get together and create another association that would do practically the same thing.

Again, you can't have discussions about this topic with most people because most people are dumbasses who don't know enough to be informed.

Hey mall cop 

 

Shut up, you don't know a damn thing about the NCAA either and have produced no facts to back anything you say up

 

And I'm smart enough to be attending the University of Florida, what second rate institution did you attend?

  • Like 1
  • Haha 1
Link to comment
Share on other sites

1 hour ago, Sweetlarry said:

Holy shit! A deadspin article?!? 
 

Fucking eh carnalito! I’m woke now! 
 

😂

In last month’s antitrust case in Oakland challenging the artificial caps on athlete compensation, the NCAA’s defense included the restatement of an imaginary economic principle that is fundamental to its existence: College athletes shouldn’t make money, the NCAA argued, because if players were paid above some magical line, consumer demand for the product would plummet and the golden goose would stop laying its billion-dollar eggs.

 
 
 

But when pressed as to where that magical line is, the answer always changes. Prior to 1956, the answer was something like “anything at all” since as an organization, the NCAA maintained that even athletic scholarships were pay and thus anyone getting an athletic scholarship had forfeited their amateurism. As economist Roger Noll testified in Oakland, by this standard, no school in Division I is presenting amateur sports, other than those in the Ivy League. (You can read the public version of Noll’s direct testimony yourself. This element of his testimony appears at pages 9 through 11.)

The thing is, though, that even way back then, the NCAA’s claim—that fan interest would evaporate if schools did not agree to cap compensation at the magical line between amateur and professional—was false. Patently, demonstrably false.

Prior to 1948, the NCAA never asserted any right to actually enforce its amateur status, leaving it to each conference to assess its own fans’ competing desires—for high quality play on the one hand and for amateurism on the other—and make offers to athletes consistent with its own assessment. Schools did different things. Big Ten schools did not give scholarships, but they gave their athletes jobs on campus. (Yes, they were employees of their schools despite Mark Emmert’s claim that such a thing is incompatible with college sports.) SEC schools gave athletic scholarships that included cash stipends. Starting in 1948, the NCAA tried, but failed to enforce its rules, and did not succeed in establishing real national oversight until 1956.

So we have a hypothesis, which just so happens to be a crux of the NCAA’s legal argument: Paying higher than the amateur line will destroy demand for college sports.

 
 
 
Link to comment
Share on other sites

2 hours ago, HooverOutlaw said:

If a well known player gets paid by a sports/card for doing an autograph signing how should that be illegal.  But by NCAA rules it is illegal and if caught the player is suspended. 

Simple.

Because it's an amateur sport.

If you want to sign autographs and make money then go play professional sports somewhere.

  • Thumbs Down 1
Link to comment
Share on other sites

52 minutes ago, BUFORDGAWOLVES said:

In last month’s antitrust case in Oakland challenging the artificial caps on athlete compensation, the NCAA’s defense included the restatement of an imaginary economic principle that is fundamental to its existence: College athletes shouldn’t make money, the NCAA argued, because if players were paid above some magical line, consumer demand for the product would plummet and the golden goose would stop laying its billion-dollar eggs.

 
 
 

But when pressed as to where that magical line is, the answer always changes. Prior to 1956, the answer was something like “anything at all” since as an organization, the NCAA maintained that even athletic scholarships were pay and thus anyone getting an athletic scholarship had forfeited their amateurism. As economist Roger Noll testified in Oakland, by this standard, no school in Division I is presenting amateur sports, other than those in the Ivy League. (You can read the public version of Noll’s direct testimony yourself. This element of his testimony appears at pages 9 through 11.)

The thing is, though, that even way back then, the NCAA’s claim—that fan interest would evaporate if schools did not agree to cap compensation at the magical line between amateur and professional—was false. Patently, demonstrably false.

Prior to 1948, the NCAA never asserted any right to actually enforce its amateur status, leaving it to each conference to assess its own fans’ competing desires—for high quality play on the one hand and for amateurism on the other—and make offers to athletes consistent with its own assessment. Schools did different things. Big Ten schools did not give scholarships, but they gave their athletes jobs on campus. (Yes, they were employees of their schools despite Mark Emmert’s claim that such a thing is incompatible with college sports.) SEC schools gave athletic scholarships that included cash stipends. Starting in 1948, the NCAA tried, but failed to enforce its rules, and did not succeed in establishing real national oversight until 1956.

So we have a hypothesis, which just so happens to be a crux of the NCAA’s legal argument: Paying higher than the amateur line will destroy demand for college sports.

 
 
 

And we have had multiple tests of that hypothesis: Many schools in major college football and basketball paid their athletes more than that.

College sports are more popular and more profitable than ever. The only scientific conclusion is to reject the hypothesis.


Rather than heed the scientific method, the NCAA’s response is always to move the goalposts. But of course the claim that people only watch college sports because the athletes are kept artificially poor is, at core, utter rubbish, and the NCAA keeps moving the magical line higher.

Starting in 1956, the NCAA defined the level of compensation beyond which one would be considered a professional as a Grant-in-Aid and set the GIA limit as tuition, fees, room, board, books and necessary supplies, plus a $15-a-month stipend. (Remember that $15 went a lot father back then. It’d be like $140 a month now). This stipend was known as “laundry money” because in the sexist culture of the 1950s, it was seen as impossible for a young man to do his own laundry, so of course he needed money to pay a woman to do it for him.

So for the period from 1956–1976, we had a test of the view that any money for athletes would kill college sports. Yet despite the scholarships and stipends, college sports remained extremely popular. So right away, this was proof that the former line, extant for a half-century, had been wrong.

Then in the 1970s, America as a whole hit a bad patch, economically. Inflation was high, growth was slow. Basically, everyone felt like they were earning less and things were costing a lot more. Schools were no different, so they gathered in Chicago in August 1975 and declared that the amateurism standard that had served the industry for the previous two decades was too generous and needed to be curtailed, lest college sports die. Not because fans felt athletes were insufficiently amateur, but rather because schools’ competitive urges were leading them to spend more than was prudent in those tough economic ties. In other words, it was a decision to fix prices to save money.

I’ve read the minutes of the meeting—they are available in hard copy at the University of New Mexico and Northwest Louisiana State – but if you don’t want to travel there, you can see some of the relevant quotes in the public version of another of the court filings in the Oakland case (read pages 51-56). If you read it, you will see that no one in the room expressed a single concern that the problem was with alienating fans. It was, in every sense, we’re spending too much money and we’d like to spend less.

There is an economic term for when a group of competitors agrees to a maximum price each will spend on a needed input to their product. The term is “cost-cutting cartel” and that is what the NCAA revealed itself to be when, starting in 1976, it rolled out its new definition of amateurism by redefining the GIA to exclude necessary supplies, to exclude any book recommended by the professor but not required, and to exclude the “laundry money” stipend.

So now we had a new hypothesis to test. If the NCAA’s assertion is that consumer demand will decline if athletes receive more than their definition of amateurism, then it should hold that when athletes received less money, demand should have immediately shot up. There is no evidence that it did. And yet that rule remained on the books as the NCAA’s definition of the line beyond which the sport would collapse, all the way up until Aug. 1, 2015, when the magical line moved yet again.

During that period from 1976 through 2015, multiple lawsuits were filed, and multiple arguments were made by the NCAA that if athletes got more than the GIA limit, the sport would collapse. In 2007, the NCAA brought out several witnesses who said that if athletes got cash payments akin to laundry money (but updated with the less sexist term of “cost of attendance” stipends), that would amount to “pay for play.” These witnesses included current NCAA VP Lynn Holzman, former NCAA VP David Berst, and expert MIT economist Jerry Hausman.

(A brief side excursion on the term “pay for play”: never use it, unless you are quoting someone. It is a term of propaganda. When a member of Congress takes a bribe, we call it “pay for play.” It connotes bribery. But in the context of 2007 or 2013, providing an athlete with a COA stipend was not a proposed bribe, it was a form of compensation for services. When you call a plumber over to fix a leaking sink, it is not “pay for plumb.” When a coach gets $10 million to coach an FBS football team it is not “pay for coach.” It’s just good ol’ American compensation. So every time you say “pay for play” you are, wittingly or unwittingly, propagating propaganda. Don’t do it.)

In 2013, the NCAA brought out expert Berkeley economist Dan Rubinfeld, former chief economist for the U.S. DOJ, who argued (under penalty of perjury) that if athletes got more than the GIA limit, then “amateur college athletics, including amateur college football and college basketball, but also including dozens of other amateur sports … would not exist.” (You can read this at page 20 of his report for the O’Bannon case.)

Well, as we know, in the wake of the O’Bannon trial, when many witnesses testified that they did not see any justification for capping pay below cost of attendance, even though the NCAA had been doing so for almost 40 years, the NCAA relented and allowed the Power 5 conferences to start paying more. Laundry money was back, baby, in the form of COA stipends which in some cases exceeded $6,000 per year.

And so we had yet another test of the NCAA’s hypothesis. And now, with more compensation allowed, college sports’ popularity did not drop and did not spike, but continued to grow at the same pace. Athletes are now being paid more, and nevertheless college sports continue to exist!

Did that make the NCAA admit their inability to identify the magical line, or admit any doubts as to whether there even was a magical line? Not at all. It denied that the change from the old cap to the new cap was even relevant because, as it now claimed, the cap did not really change at all. The explanation for this stretches belief. Beginning in 2004, schools had been allowed to give the most academically gifted athletes an income supplement from an academic scholarship to provide that COA stipend, so the fact that in 2015, suddenly everyone was getting the stipend was not a change at all.

This does not demonstrate what the NCAA thinks it does. If the change came in 2004, then the fact that NO ONE EVEN NOTICED is very strong evidence that the 1976 line was wrong. But back in 2004, of course, the argument was that it was okay because this supplemental income was unrelated to athletics, and indeed, it was alleged that if every athlete, not just those on academic scholarships, could get their full COA, it would be “pay for play”—exactly what happened in 2015, when the NCAA would retroactively claim that universally available COA stipends were simply status quo.


See what’s going on here? No matter what the prior justification was for the position of magical line, when the line changes the argument becomes that we all simply misunderstood the old line. This is gaslighting—when a person or organization in power tells you that your own memory of a contradiction is faulty, that rather than their having been wrong, you are the one who’s failing to remember how things really were, and thus can’t understand how they are now.

Here is what NCAA gaslighting looked like in the recent court case in Oakland, where University of Virginia economist Kenneth Elzinga claimed that the NCAA rules on what constitutes the magic line had never changed during the hundred years of history I’ve laid out above.

Elzinga testified (on pages 19-20), emphasis his:

The essential features or goals of the NCAA’s amateurism definition have remained consistent. When one compares the language of the NCAA’s current definition of amateurism to the definition adopted in 1912, the language is similar… The essential features of both definitions are the same. First, student-athletes are those who play the game for the sake of the game, i.e., “for the exercise, training, and social pleasures,” or for the “education and . . . physical, mental and social benefits.” Second, student-athletes do not play for “any material or economic advantage or reward,” or “for pay in any form.” That is, they do not play for pay. These two strands are not separate; they are complementary. The opposite of playing for pay is to play for the sake of the game and vice versa. Both definitions refer to the attitude or state of mind of the student-athlete. The earlier definition says “[t]he natural or primary attitude of mind and motives in play determines amateurism,” and the latter says “tudent participation in intercollegiate athletics is an avocation.”

Do you see where he’s sneaking a rabbit into his testimonial hat? He’s not saying the RULES didn’t change—the actual definition of the magic line—he’s just saying the justification has never changed. In both 1912 and 2018, the NCAA has claimed that if they don’t restrict earnings, athletes will not be amateurs. But Elzinga’s testimony does not engage with where that slippery line might be.

The line even changed during the course of Elzinga’s work on the case. In his first report in the matter, he explained that even “a penny” of non-educational compensation would destroy demand for college sports.

But when confronted with evidence that many athletes already get hundreds of dollars of such non-educational compensation, he denied having meant it, claiming he was being taken too literally, that he was quoting someone else, and, anyway, some token payment above the magical line was fine. You can see the goalposts moving if you compare his early testimony to the revised version he submitted a year later in the run-up to the trial itself, where he testified (on page 32), emphasis mine:

“Once a student-athlete’s cost of attendance and the amounts incidental to his or her participation in college athletics have been covered, to receive additional amounts in return for athletic performance is to be paid, i.e., to cease to be an amateur and to become a professional.”

That’s a pro-NCAA economist changing his definition of the magical line in real-time.

This goalpost-shifting can also be seen in the testimony of NCAA VP Kevin Lennon. In the run-up to the trial, at an unguarded moment (under oath) Lennon had testified (at pages 72-73) that these sorts of additional payments (what the NCAA calls “benefits incidental to participation”) are “not related to the principle of amateurism.”

A month or two later, as the implications of this admission became more evident, Lennon was asked to submit a lawyer-drafted recantation, in which he explained that he only meant that “granular changes to certain NCAA rules could be made without impacting amateurism...In other instances, however, the proposed benefit may pose a greater risk to amateurism as a potential device for pay-for-play, requiring the membership to adopt limits to minimize that risk.”

In other words, how could you possibly think that when he said the rules about paying athletes with Xboxes for going to a bowl game were “not related to the principle of amateurism,” that he possibly meant anything other than that those rules are totally related to preserving amateurism? Gaslighting.

Another piece of evidence brought up in Oakland was the notion that from 1956 forward, once the NCAA grabbed the power to enforce its magic line du jour, schools frequently broke the rules. Athletes lost their eligibility, and even once, when SMU was found to have egregiously flaunted the rules, it was banned from having a football team for two years, the so-called death penalty.

In his testimony (at pages 51-55), Roger Noll rightly pointed to these as examples of the magical line being crossed without harm to fans’ interest in college sports. College football is orders of magnitude bigger now than it was when SMU was executed, and has thrived in the face of numerous programs committing violations.

My favorite example of this sort of “scandal” was when Ohio State players had the temerity to sell their own property to pay for tattoos, and were suspended for half a season—an extreme penalty in the NCAA system—but were allowed to play in the Sugar Bowl against Arkansas because everyone wanted to see that looming clash of the titans. The TV ratings were historic because it promised to be the highest quality of football. No one seemed to care that a large chunk of the Ohio State players were not amateurs under the rule in place at the time.

In the Oakland case, Professor Elzinga provided the sleight-of-hand needed to explain this away too. What mattered was not whether there were infractions here or there, but just that the public knew that the NCAA was on the beat, patrolling to make sure it only happened occasionally, and that when it was caught, it was punished severely. Each example was therefore not evidence disproving the hypothesis, but supporting it. He testified (at page 36):

“Even if rising revenues did establish that punishing rules violators has not undermined the popularity of college sports, that would not support a conclusion that fans of college sports do not care about amateurism. The fact that the NCAA conducted those investigations demonstrates to the public that the NCAA does take amateurism seriously, and is willing to mete out punishment when violations call for it. That’s the sort of information that should be more likely to encourage the public about NCAA enforcement, rather than discourage it.”


And so we come to the scandal of the day, the criminal fraud and corruption cases currently being tried in federal court in New York City, in which several non-NCAA members are accused of defrauding major college basketball programs by providing side payments to athletes to ensure they attended those schools. The government’s theory is basically nuts, because it relies on the premise that when a sneaker company pays an athlete to go to a school that wears that company’s shoes, that school is somehow harmed—of course, we all know that schools hate getting great athletes who can pack their arenas and help generate donations.

Both the government and the defendants in the case admit that money was given to athletes. In some cases, these athletes played for those schools—e.g., Dennis Smith played a year for N.C. State and the Federal Government alleges, and the defendants do not dispute, that he received $40,000 on top of his scholarship to do so. He was, so to speak, paid and he played. And no one cared. Where’s the magical line?

Smith finished his college career without detection by the NCAA’s beat cops. The allegation of Smith’s payment was leveled a year ago. N.C. State has not been charged with an NCAA violation. N.C. State has not seen its fans storm to the athletic department offices and demand that the AD or the compliance staff be fired for failing to catch this egregious violation. No. One. Cares.

So what should we expect to see when college basketball tips off next month?

If you believe the NCAA’s “amateurism” hypothesis, it’s now clear that many of the best athletes in college basketball were paid by third parties to play for their AAU teams, and many were also paid to choose a school based on the shoe company those schools have contract with, so the inescapable result is that consumer demand for college basketball will plummet because of systemic payment above the magic line that was not kept under control by rigorous NCAA enforcement efforts.

Once again, the “Amateurism is Essential” argument will be put to the test. Be ready for it, because if the NCAA is correct, then College Basketball May Die Next Month. People might boycott in droves. And if so, the elusive magical line will finally have been found.

But if instead what we see is business as usual, maybe this time we’ll finally stop accepting the ever-shifting goalposts, the amateurism gaslighting, and just acknowledge that what fans care about is college sports played by college athletes, no matter what they’re earning.


Andy Schwarz is an antitrust economist and partner at OSKR, an economic consulting firm specializing in expert witness testimony. He is part of a new project, HBLeague.com, working to create a non-amateur version of college sports. Follow him on Twitter, @andyhre.

SHARE TH

Quit spamming the board with this shit. 
 

Where is the money coming from to pay everybody? We paying schollie athletes only? Stars? Sliding scale? What about other sports? They get paid? They even exist? 
 

The one thing most forget is college is about education. The dumbasses who don’t get degrees fail themselves. I’d be for creating a minor league system separate from colleges for all sports. 
 

paying college athletes is just a hard pass. When the 99+% of kids who don’t make it professionally fail I’m sure they’ll be plenty of low paying, no skill jobs to scoop them up. 

Link to comment
Share on other sites

3 minutes ago, Sweetlarry said:

Quit spamming the board with this shit. 
 

Where is the money coming from to pay everybody? We paying schollie athletes only? Stars? Sliding scale? What about other sports? They get paid? They even exist? 
 

The one thing most forget is college is about education. The dumbasses who don’t get degrees fail themselves. I’d be for creating a minor league system separate from colleges for all sports. 
 

paying college athletes is just a hard pass. When the 99+% of kids who don’t make it professionally fail I’m sure they’ll be plenty of low paying, no skill jobs to scoop them up. 

Trying to copy and paste the shit for you to read it dammit. 
Don’t get your tampon twisted up. 
 

bgw

Link to comment
Share on other sites

5 hours ago, BUFORDGAWOLVES said:

Slave wages off the backs of these athletes so coaches can make millions. 
 

The plantation has moved from the fields Of agriculture to the fields of play. 
 

Only difference is the whip, chains and kidnapping didn’t take place, but had other controls such as coach discretion to transfer destination and other overseer activities. 
 

Purely transactional on all levels, NCAA is killing it at the register and once again... White men are running the plantation. 
 

bgw

And so they can dismiss all of those claims by getting out of the sports-for-big $ business. Just step away. Of course,  I doubt they have the guts to do that. 

Link to comment
Share on other sites

4 hours ago, The Guru said:

It's actually pretty simple.

If someone would take your place, and do it for free, then you can't form a union and you have no real argument regarding it being employment.

This is the case at thousands of colleges and universities across the country.

There are hundreds, probably thousands, of former high school football players walking every campus in this country that would play this game for free if given the opportunity.

Heck, dozens of players on each roster do that right now.

The slavery allegory is a disgrace and an embarrassment to anybody who uses it.

I've made every effort to listen to voices like those of Jay Bilas on the matter. But, there is no getting around the truth of what you say here.

Link to comment
Share on other sites

22 minutes ago, Sweetlarry said:

Quit spamming the board with this shit. 
 

Where is the money coming from to pay everybody? We paying schollie athletes only? Stars? Sliding scale? What about other sports? They get paid? They even exist? 
 

The one thing most forget is college is about education. The dumbasses who don’t get degrees fail themselves. I’d be for creating a minor league system separate from colleges for all sports. 
 

paying college athletes is just a hard pass. When the 99+% of kids who don’t make it professionally fail I’m sure they’ll be plenty of low paying, no skill jobs to scoop them up. 

Dear Dumbassery,

NCAA is not going anywhere, largest farm system in the world excepting baseball. Baseball has its own farm system. 
Espn pays out millions to SEC and now the ACC. BigTen has own network that shells out 126 million to members annually and the NCAA cuts a check to members. However the P5 have the most clout. 
 

Are you really this far behind on all of this and possess the biggest mouth? Tried to help your fucking ass, and this is what I get?

Just curious,

bgw

Link to comment
Share on other sites

14 minutes ago, badrouter said:

And so they can dismiss all of those claims by getting out of the sports-for-big $ business. Just step away. Of course,  I doubt they have the guts to do that. 

Most likely not, just be equitable. There’s been movement in P5 , depending on student distance from home. Big moneymaker. 
Shitty sports medicine at these big schools, quack team doctors and lousy trainers that look the other way and sweep injuries under the rug.

 

bgw

Link to comment
Share on other sites

1 hour ago, Columbiafan said:

Hey mall cop 

 

Shut up, you don't know a damn thing about the NCAA either and have produced no facts to back anything you say up

 

And I'm smart enough to be attending the University of Florida, what second rate institution did you attend?

Screw y'all for beating us in the national championship for basketball and football in the same year!

  • Haha 1
Link to comment
Share on other sites

19 minutes ago, BUFORDGAWOLVES said:

Shitty sports medicine at these big schools, quack team doctors and lousy trainers that look the other way and sweep injuries under the rug.

What kind of nonsense are you speaking?

😄

These players receive some of the best medical treatment and sports medicine training in the entire world.

  • Thumbs Down 1
Link to comment
Share on other sites

Join the conversation

You can post now and register later. If you have an account, sign in now to post with your account.

Guest
Reply to this topic...

×   Pasted as rich text.   Paste as plain text instead

  Only 75 emoji are allowed.

×   Your link has been automatically embedded.   Display as a link instead

×   Your previous content has been restored.   Clear editor

×   You cannot paste images directly. Upload or insert images from URL.

  • Recently Browsing   0 members

    • No registered users viewing this page.
×
×
  • Create New...